Workshop on Innovation and Telecommunications Policy

Innovation and Telecommunications Policy WorkshopWhat should be the role for telecommunications policy? What should top Canada’s telecommunications policy agenda?

Those topics are being explored in a workshop hosted by the Ivey Business School in Toronto. “Innovation and Telecommunications Policy: Shaping Tech, Markets & Networks”, Ivey’s fourth workshop on telecommunications policy, will take place in the afternoon of Wednesday, May 21, at Ivey’s Donald K. Johnson Centre in downtown Toronto.

As noted on the workshop’s website, telecommunications policy traditionally focuses on competition, affordability, digital divide and access. Far less attention has been spent on how telecom policy can be used to develop innovation and new technologies for economic growth.

It is crucial for Canada to be developing policies and strategies that support investment in digital infrastructure. Innovation and economic progress is crucial for Canada (and other countries) in the wake of global trade disruption and geopolitical challenges.

Frequent readers know that I have been calling for a refresh of Canada’s digital agenda for a long time. Late last year, when I was checking my scorecard against my 2024 policy agenda, I noticed that there was some overlap with what is planned for the workshop. I continue to have concerns about driving increased adoption. Not enough work is being done to identify (and solve) those factors that inhibit a subset of Canadians from getting online.

The half-day workshop will be held in downtown Toronto, starting with lunch at noon and running until approximately 6:00pm. Lunch will be provided and there will be a networking reception at the end of the day. In between there will be multiple keynote speakers and panel sessions looking at such questions as:

  • Will 6G be another “G” or just fizzle out?
  • How are AI and quantum communications shaping infrastructure needs?
  • How are big tech, application providers and telecom operators driving innovation?
  • Innovation, affordability and digital divide: are there trade-offs?
  • And more!

While we are one the topic of technology policy, there was a recent session hosted by AEI on the subject, “Dignity and Dynamism: The Future of Conservative Technology Policy”. You can find the replay here.

I’ll provide more details about the Ivey session as the agenda [download pdf] firms up. The last Ivey workshop was sold out, so be sure to make your plans to attend. I hope to see you May 21.

The CRTC’s 2025 Telecommunications Market Report

Canadian Telecommunications Market Report 2025The CRTC recently released its “Canadian Telecommunications Market Report 2025”, available online or as a 73-page 1.0 MB downloadable pdf.

You may recall that last year, the CRTC released its Market report, labelled as “Annual highlights of the telecommunications sector 2022”, and as you will see, it can be found among the 2023 files on the CRTC website. This year’s edition is found among the 2025 files, but contains market data from 2023. Confused?

In the Executive Summary of the report, the CRTC recognized the importance of encouraging investment, but in some ways, it failed to draw a line between investment and the need for high EBITDA margins. The Commission wrote “A central challenge for the CRTC is to incentivize providers to invest, while allowing new competitors access to their networks to provide more affordable choices to Canadians.” The report observes that among comparator countries (Australia, France, Germany, Italy, Japan, and the United States), “Canada’s telecommunications service sector shows among the highest levels of capital expenditures.”

The CRTC’s Market Report could be more precise in its use of language to be more objective in its presentation of the data. For example, the Competition section of the Executive Summary leads with “Canada’s telecommunications industry has expanded to several Internet and cellphone service providers. However, a small group of large service providers maintain commanding market shares and continue to report high profit margins.”

What does this mean? How are we supposed to interpret this? Why start that sentence with “However”?

In Section 4.2 of the report, the CRTC states “Canadians benefit from competition when there is a range of service options and providers of various sizes competing in the market.” Can someone point me to an economics text that says an indicator of a markets level of competitiveness is the variety of size of service providers? Ted Woodhead suggests “It would appear that CRTC believes the ideal state would be to have a large group of small service providers with low market shares reporting low profit margins.”

Let’s look a little more closely at “a small group of large service providers maintain commanding market shares and continue to report high profit margins”. Later in the report, we see that “profit margins” are defined as EBITDA (earnings before interest, taxes, depreciation and amortization). The report leaves the reader with the impression that these EBITDA profit margins are too high, which ignores the actual financial challenges being faced by Canada’s facilities-based carriers. That is misleading. EBITDA, by definition, is a measure before taking into account interest, taxes, depreciation, and amortization. For capital-intensive businesses, EBITDA simply doesn’t reflect business profitability, especially in times of rising interest rates and high levels of investment.

The Executive Summary goes on to say “In the last two years, Internet and cellphone prices have declined nearly 10%, and roughly 25% respectively. However, Canadians have noted the opposite, with many seeing higher bills. This may be explained by some Canadians paying for more data and faster speeds.”

“May be explained”? Come on now. The phenomenon of higher bills is fully explained by customers choosing to buy higher value plans.

Let’s take a look at the data. In Figure 15, the CRTC shows some pretty significant changes in internet services prices between 2020 and 2024. In the case of 50 Mbps service, the monthly price dropped 27.4%; Gigabit per second services fell 35.6% during the same period. In Figure 16, the drop for the Internet Price Index over that same period is less dramatic, at 10.6%.

Prices for specific plans dropped more significantly than the Statistics Canada Internet Price Index. How do we account for the discrepancy?

Clearly, as the prices for various speeds fall, households are migrating to faster services, changing the norm. Figure 27 provides evidence of that migration. In 2020, only 1 in 12 households (8.3%) subscribed to gigabit internet service; just 3 years later, by 2023, more than a quarter of Canadian households (25.7%) subscribed to gig services.

On the wireless side, the same effect can be observed in Figure 43. The price for a 10 GB plan dropped nearly 60%, from $69.42 to $28.03. The 50 GB plan fell by more than two thirds, from $124.28 to $39.94. During the same period, Figure 55 shows a migration to higher capacity mobile plans.

Why would the CRTC cast shade over the fact that prices have gone down? Its phrase “Canadians have noted the opposite” should have been written as “Canadians have incorrectly noted the opposite”. Why would the CRTC be peddling public opinion – urban legends – along side of hard data? The facts show prices have gone down significantly. Why isn’t the CRTC clearly dispelling misperceptions about prices instead of contributing to the confusion? 

If you can read past the biased commentary, the Canadian Telecommunications Market Report 2025 is a valuable collection of authoritative data. Just be prepared to read a report that was written with a not-so-hidden agenda.

Foreign ownership restrictions in turbulent times

In view of the current international trade tensions, what are your thoughts on foreign ownership restrictions in Canadian telecom?

That was a question posed to me earlier this week. Over the years, I’ve talked about foreign ownership more than 200 times, so I’d like to hear your thoughts. View this as an invitation to share your thoughts as a comment.

Canadian FlagLet’s start by clarifying the current rules, which are often misunderstood. Ownership and Control restrictions are set out in Section 16 of the Telecommunications Act.

In Section 16(2)c), we see that there are no ownership restrictions if the company “has annual revenues from the provision of telecommunications services in Canada that represent less than 10% of the total annual revenues, as determined by the Commission, from the provision of telecommunications services in Canada.” In Section 16(6) we see that the company can grow beyond 10% of the telecom market, as long as it grows beyond that threshold organically (ie. not by acquisition).

Earlier this week, the CRTC released the 2023 market size as $59.6B, meaning the 10% threshold is just shy of $6B. There are only 3 companies in Canada with telecom revenues exceeding 10% of the total market: Bell, Rogers, and TELUS.

Number 4 player Quebecor (Videotron) reported revenues of just over $4.8B in 2024. Other than Bell, Rogers and TELUS, foreign acquisition is permissible. A foreign-owned service provider could be built or assembled by acquisitions (up to $5.96B in revenues) and then grown.

Keep in mind that broadcasting has its own restrictions, creating a “poisoned pill” for most converged communications companies, since broadcast distribution (cable or IPTV) is regulated under the Broadcasting Act. There are various creative corporate structures that could enable a competitor to work around the broadcast issues.

What are your thoughts? Would Canada’s communications infrastructure face increased risk of disruption with lightened foreign ownership restrictions? Benefits? Risks? Are concerns real?

Please leave a comment. You don’t have to use your real name, but I do require a real email address (which won’t be posted).

The inefficiencies of regulatory arbitrage

It is has been about 5 years since I last wrote about regulatory arbitrage. When I have written about the subject in the past, it was in the context of telecom, with arbitragers exploiting loopholes in certain mandated rates.

However, regulatory arbitrage also applies on the broadcast side of the CRTC and it isn’t just a Canadian problem.

A recent article on the Truth on the Markets blog was written about FCC regulations in the US, but most of the article applies equally in Canada.

The article talks about differences in regulating traditional broadcasters as contrasted with unregulated streaming services. “While consumers increasingly access video content through streaming platforms subject to minimal oversight, legacy media providers continue to operate under restrictive regulatory frameworks designed for a bygone era. This regulatory asymmetry creates economic inefficiencies and distorts competition.”

Sounds familiar, right? Canadians wouldn’t know that the author, Eric Fruits of the International Center for Law and Economics, was talking about FCC regulations in this article, rather than the CRTC.

“The inefficiencies of regulatory arbitrage multiply when different services that serve similar functions—such as broadcast, cable, and streaming—are regulated under different frameworks. As technologies converge, disparities among the regimes erected to regulate those technologies become increasingly problematic.”

There are two ways to address the regulatory imbalance: one could lessen the regulatory burden on legacy broadcasters now that streaming services are in a position to discipline the market; or, one could increase the level of regulation on the streaming services. Canada has been moving toward option two – adding fees and content regulations to streaming services.

Of course, increased regulation of streaming services is bound to have a deleterious impact on innovation.

Dr. Fruits writes that regulatory arbitrage won’t improve economic welfare if it shifts investments based on regulatory considerations, rather than marketplace conditions. As an example, he cites the migration of certain premium content from broadcast and cable to streaming services being driven only partly by consumer preferences. He says it’s being influenced by the advantages of operating in the less-regulated online space.

ICLE is participating in the CRTC’s public notice, “The Path Forward – Working towards a sustainable Canadian broadcasting system” [2025-2], with a public hearing scheduled for May 12. Its submission sets out a belief that a framework emphasizing “market efficiency, competition, and regulatory proportionality supports the need for deregulation and light-touch solutions.”

As an example, ICLE looks at the 1:1 rule, which requires BDUs to distribute an independent programming service for each affiliated service carried.

With near-guaranteed carriage, independent services have less incentive to invest in marketing, production quality, or audience analytics—factors critical to organic growth. Furthermore, BDUs often pass the costs of mandatory carriage on to consumers through bundled pricing. This results in cross-subsidization, whereby popular services indirectly fund niche offerings that might otherwise fail in a competitive market.

ICLE’s “Strategic Recommendations for the CRTC” within its submission in the 2025-2 proceeding ties back to the theme of regulatory arbitrage. “The history of video-market regulation suggests that static regulatory frameworks often struggle to keep pace with dynamic markets, leading to unintended consequences. Regulations that might be appropriate given current technology and market conditions can quickly become obsolete or counterproductive as markets evolve.”

The submission concludes: “As the CRTC works toward a sustainable Canadian broadcasting system, it should take a light-touch and modest approach that acknowledges the existing dynamic and competitive video-distribution environment, and the nearly impossible task of predicting and responding to ongoing rapid technological and market advancements.”

The Truth on the Market article talks about technology bringing the end of “scarcity” in the video services business. “Policymakers and regulators evaluating competition in video markets face a seeming paradox: so many monopolies, or near-monopolies, but so much competition.” From a consumer perspective, the video services market is no longer limited to TV channels. This will clearly confound simplistic analysis by those seeking government intervention to disrupt so-called monopoly or duopoly service providers.

So many monopolies, or near-monopolies, yet so much competition.

Will the CRTC exhibit the kind of confidence required to let the system and the marketplace work with a lighter regulatory touch?

The high cost of serving high cost areas

Last May, I discussed an interesting CRTC proceeding looking at high cost serving areas.

At the time, I described an interesting CRTC proceeding underway to examine the future of voice telephone service to a total of 110 households and 5 businesses located in 8 communities served by 3 telephone exchanges located off the beaten track in British Columbia. The communities are connected to the TELUS backbone network using microwave radio links using the 3500MHz band. The radio systems used in these communities are outdated, manufacturer discontinued, so the equipment is no longer supported. Indeed, the manufacturer (SR Telecom) went bankrupt more than 15 years ago. As if that wasn’t enough, the 3500MHz band is being reallocated by ISED.

ISED told TELUS that it could no longer guarantee its use of the spectrum beyond the end of March, 2025.

So a year ago, TELUS told their remaining subscribers that it would be sending each one $1400, enough to pay to get connected to a satellite-based voice-over-IP service. That amount would cover the costs of the equipment, installation and the service fees for a full year. TELUS filed its plan with the CRTC in May, 2024, which is what stimulated my high cost blog post last year.

The CRTC decision on the matter was released two weeks ago, which is what brings us to today’s story.

Basically, the CRTC agreed with TELUS that it is not viable to modify (and maintain) the SR Telecom equipment operating on another frequency. The CRTC agreed that satellite-based VoIP was a reasonable substitute, but was concerned with the monthly price differential after the initial gift of $1400 runs out. So, the CRTC awarded residents an additional $4,428. That amount represents 3 years of the price differential between current rates of $32 per month, compared to a total of $155 per month for a satellite-based VoIP service. Never mind the fact that these households will effectively be getting residential broadband for free as part of the deal.

The CRTC basically waved its hands over the contentious issue of whether the “Obligation to Serve” continues to exist for these communities. The Commission acknowledged that TELUS tariffs contain an explicit exception “when it cannot acquire or maintain the equipment or rights of access that are necessary to provide service.” And the decision itself agrees that the status quo is not viable.

  1. While the Commission agrees with TELUS that there are limits to the obligation to serve, the Commission considers that the obligation continues to apply when there is a loss of access to spectrum or other existing facilities. All facilities will eventually require replacement due to technological advancements and regular wear and tear. If the obligation to serve no longer applied when a provider was unable to maintain its facilities, this would effectively time-limit the obligation to serve. This would be particularly problematic in high-cost serving areas. Instead, the Commission considers that ILECs are obligated to serve where they can reasonably replace those facilities or find alternative methods to serve customers.

The Commission seems to have forgotten that the Obligation to Serve comes from an era that included a subsidy for high cost serving areas. Expenditures to build and maintain infrastructure were recovered from a kind of regulatory tax on other service and other regions – the national contribution fund in later years.

Once again, the CRTC is demonstrating that it lacks appropriate tools to deal with high monthly costs on an ongoing basis for certain remote communities. For a number of years, I have written about what the CRTC itself recognized as a consequence of its 2016 Broadband Decision.

As I wrote in 2020:

Many people didn’t give much thought to what the CRTC termed a consequence of that decision, “As a result, the Commission will begin to phase out the subsidy that supports local telephone service.” In other words, the Commission swapped out a program for ongoing support for all high cost serving areas, in favour of awarding one-time payments to specific winning projects.

I wrote about the CRTC’s former high cost serving area subsidy regime in my post about wealth redistribution last month. In today’s case, the CRTC decided that TELUS should cover the shortfall, now that the Commission’s own subsidy regime has collapsed.

The decision’s analysis of the Obligation to Serve strikes me as overly simplistic. The Decision says “the Commission considers that ILECs are obligated to serve where they can reasonably replace those facilities or find alternative methods to serve customers”. Then, the CRTC agrees that TELUS cannot reasonably replace those facilities, but still maintain that TELUS has an ongoing obligation to serve. The alternative is another facilities-based service provider: Starlink. Why is TELUS still involved?

To its credit, the CRTC found that a third-party satellite-based VoIP service was a satisfactory solution for service continuity for these communities, similar to a finding 2 years ago when Bell withdrew its exchange radio service.

The total amount we are talking about here is just half a million dollars (115 households at $4,428 each). A court challenge could easily cost that and more. Is this a precedent that TELUS will allow to stand? How many other communities will be left in a similar situation across the country because of the CRTC’s decision in 2016 “to phase out the subsidy that supports local telephone service”? Why is Starlink considered to be an appropriate solution for these communities, but not for the 3 communities I described a month ago in “Fifteen million of other people’s money”?

That particular decision really needs to be revisited.

The CRTC is continuing to be quite comfortable spending other people’s money. Are Canadians getting value?

Scroll to Top